By: Sean G. King, JD,
CPA, MAcc
General Counsel, Tennessee Bitcoin Alliance
Valuing bitcoins is a controversial subject. Part of the problem is that traditional valuation tools (discounted cash flows, for example) simply are not helpful when applied to something like bitcoins. Much more on this subject here.
Does this mean that bitcoins cannot be fundamentally or
intrinsically valued? I don’t think
so.
Starting at the Right Point
Most attempts at valuing bitcoins start at the wrong
beginning point. They assume individual
bitcoins to be discrete assets distinct from the Bitcoin network itself. Consequently, they attempt to ascertain the
value of individual bitcoins by reference or analogy to other discrete
assets--usually precious metals, fiat currencies, money, land, etc.—rather than
by appraising bitcoins for what they are, the exclusive means of access to the benefits
of the Bitcoin network itself.
In some ways bitcoins are analogous to shares of stock. Shares of stock give their owners legal rights
to certain benefits of the company (such as a share of the profits),
enforceable by courts of law. Similarly bitcoins give their owners certain practical abilities (specifically, accessibility
to the Bitcoin network), enforceable by mathematical formulas embedded in the
network itself. Just as individual
stocks are best characterized as transferable rights of access to, or ownership
of, the benefits of a company, individual bitcoins are best characterized as a
means of obtaining certain benefits that are only available to those with access
to the Bitcoin network.
Top Down, not Bottom
Up
The intrinsic value of a share of stock depends ultimately
upon the value of the company. We don’t
value a share of stock by comparing it, by analogy, to other shares of stock or
other assets classes, and then summing the value of all the individual shares
to arrive at the value of the company.
Doing so gives no consideration to the unique attributes of the company
itself (profits, free cash flow, competitive position, etc.).
So, instead, we determine the value of the company, the
enterprise itself, and then divide by the number of shares to arrive at a per
share value. Each share thus represents
a fractional interest in the company’s whole value. Said another way, each
share’s value is determined by reference to the whole.
For the same reason that we cannot value shares without
determining the enterprise value of the underlying business, we cannot value
bitcoins without first referencing the underlying value of the Bitcoin network.
The Bitcoin community’s failure to understand this has lead to endless debates
over the origins of value (subjective versus objective), whether or not
bitcoins are money, the significance of Mises’s regression theorem,
etc. These debates resolve themselves once
we start from the proper beginning—valuing the network.
How to Value a Network
How to value a computer network has actually been the
subject of considerable study.
The world has long recognized that networks in general, and
computer networks in particular, have practical use value, and that their usefulness
varies primarily with the size of the network as determined by its number of
nodes or users. Tiny but useful networks
have a tiny (though non-zero) value, while large and useful ones have an
exponentially larger value.
Metcalfe’s
law (articulated first around 1980 specifically as a tool for valuing
networks) teaches that the intrinsic “value”, or usefulness, of a network
varies with the square of the number of nodes in the network. Doubling the number of nodes therefore
quadruples the network’s use value, because doubling the nodes results in approximately
four times as many possible unique connections among them. For Metcalfe, the
number of possible connections available on a network was a proxy for its
usefulness, and its usefulness was a proxy for its value.
Metcalfe’s Law has been criticized primarily on three
grounds. First, in its original form, it
simply counted the number of nodes (users) rather than the number of active nodes. Thus it seemingly failed to account for the
fact that a large network that is infrequently used (that is, comprised of a
great mainly inactive or underactive nodes) may be less useful, perhaps substantially
less so, than a smaller network with almost exclusively highly active nodes.
Second, Metcalfe’s formulation assumed that each node/user
is to be equally valued, whereas Zipf’s law teaches that
this is almost certainly never the case.
Zipf’s law implies that the first most active user of a network is likely
twice as active/valuable as the second most active user, three times as
active/valuable as the third most active user, etc.
Third, application of Metcalfe’s law to large and rapidly
growing networks leads to value calculations that are unimaginably, and therefore
unrealistically, large (as we will see below).
To remedy these criticisms, commentators,
including Metcalfe, have suggested the logic of Zipf’s law requires the use value
of a network to vary not in proportion to the square of the number of its nodes
(at Metcalfe originally theorized), but rather in proportion to the number of
nodes multiplied by the log of the number of nodes [the so-called “n log(n)”
valuation metric]. For reasons we shall see, the n log(n) valuation methodology
seems to be a preferable method for valuing Bitcoin.
Relative Value
Versus Actual Value
Both Metcalfe’s Law and the n log(n) formulation (hereafter
collectively called “power law valuation metrics”) purport to tell us the relative value of a network at given
points in time based on changes in its number of users/nodes. For instance, if a network with a starting
value of “x” doubles its nodes, its value will more than double under each
approach, the two approaches varying only their respective estimations of how
much more. But, importantly, neither can
tell us the actual intrinsic value of a network unless we already know its use value
at some given point in time. One needs a
starting point value (“x”) from which to extrapolate using the power law
valuation metrics. For this, we must
rely upon other means, or else simply make some assumptions.
Bitcoin’s “X” Value
Can one calculate a definite value for Bitcoin at some
historical point in time (“x”) from which we could then extrapolate past or future
values using Metcalfe’s law and/or the n log(n) formation? Perhaps, though
doing so is certainly beyond the capabilities of this writer. Even so, we can say a few important things
about Bitcoin’s “x” value.
First, we can say with confidence that bitcoin has an “x”
value. Even the early Bitcoin network
was useful, if only to few knowledgeable insiders at first. It was useful because Bitcoin operates on a first-of-its-kind
protocol permitting computer networks to do things never
before possible. Specifically, the
Bitcoin network allows an unlimited number of people to have equal and full
access (administrator level privileges) to a common and accessible database without any of them having the practical
ability to alter any entries that came before (at least without being
discovered by all users), and without
that database being under any party’s centralized control.
To illustrate how this works, suppose that you want everyone
in the world (who so desires) to vote anonymously, using his or computers or
smart phones, as to whether or not Pluto should be classified as a planet. Assume further that you want every voter to
see every vote (though not who cast it) in real time via the web, and that you
don’t want any voter to be able to change a vote previously cast by another (at
least not without being discovered by every other voter). How would you accomplish such a thing?
Prior to Bitcoin, there was only one answer: Hire a trusted third party (someone who
everyone hopes will not manipulate the vote and who can be trusted to prevent
all other voters from doing the same) to host and secure the voting database on
its server, and to publish the results in real time.
But introducing this trusted third party adds much risk,
complexity and cost. Perhaps the additional
risk and cost is not great for something as trivial as voting on the status of
Pluto, but what if instead of tracking Pluto votes the third party’s database
was expected to track how much money each of us has in our respective bank
accounts, and any payments between us?
In that case, concerns that the trusted third party (a bank,
let’s say) might not be so trustworthy heighten immediately, right? So much so that we only permit certain third
parties (banks and money transmitters, or instance) to act in this capacity,
and we require them to obtain very expensive licenses to do so. We further require that such licensees undergo
independent CPA’s audits each year, that the CPA’s auditing the bank themselves
undergo periodic audits (“peer reviews”), that governmental or
pseudo-governmental agencies (like the Comptroller of Currency, the Federal
Reserve, the Treasury Department, state banking regulators, etc.) also audit
and “regulate” banks, and that these regulators themselves undergo periodic
audits (such as by the Governmental Accountability Office). And yet, even that is
not enough! As a final measure, we
require that an agency implicitly backed by the full faith and credit of the federal
government (the FDIC) insure certain bank deposits against our “trusted” third
party’s incompetence, theft, or failure to account for them properly.
As a society, we pay handsomely for these “trusted” third
party services, and for all the regulation and oversight that goes into to
ginning up sufficient public “trust” in them.
And, as a society, we are regularly disappointed by them.
Importantly, Bitcoin technology allows us for the first time
to hold our Pluto vote, or (once-scaled, as it has now) even securely track
people’s account balances, without having to rely on any trusted third party record
keeper (or their auditors or regulators) to ensure an accurate accounting. This never-before-possible ability for multiple
members of the public to be awarded full administrator’s privileges to a widely-accessible
database--without risk of any of them altering prior entries and without having
to place that database under the control of a “trusted” and centralized third
party to secure it—means that most every trust-based business model—those of trust
companies, brokers, exchanges, registrars, escrow agents, clearing houses,
money transferors, and banks just to name a few—can now be replicated using inexpensive
and freely-available software.
Because the Bitcoin network, though not operated, controlled
or managed by any centralized person or entity, is capable of faithfully
logging events and clearing transactions in a way that is incorruptible,
uncensorable, irreversible, completely reliable, and accessible to all (or at
least anyone owning some fraction of a bitcoin), it, or something very much
like it, will ultimately do to financial and trust-based intermediaries what
the Internet did to book and music stores, the publishing industry, the post
office, producers and processors of photographic film, newspapers, classified
ads, proprietary telephone networks, etc.
Mises’s Regression Theorum
Being a first-of-its-kind technology with obvious
usefulness, even the earliest and tiniest version of the Bitcoin network therefore
had a non-zero use value, or “x” value. And because individual bitcoins are absolutely
required to make use of the network (they are what give one administrator-level
privileges) and are limited in number, they too had a non-zero “x” value (even
in the beginning).
This is important to Austrian school economists since, for
them, whether or not bitcoin every had an initial use value, and “x” value, bears
directly on the issue of whether individual bitcoins will ever trade in the economy
as real “money”. The Austrian school of economics
teaches that only things that were once useful to some humans (for purely
practical reasons) can ever hope to become useful as money. Individual bitcoins satisfy this theoretical
requirement since, being the only way one can make entries into the secure
Bitcoin database, they have obvious practical use value.
We Don’t Know “X”,
So Now What?
We don’t necessarily need to know the Bitcoin network’s starting
“x” value to imply its value today, or at any point in time in the past or
future. Per Metcalfe’s law and/or the n log(n) formulation (again, I will refer
to the two of them collectively as the “power law valuation metrics”), its
sufficient that we know its use value at any
point in time. For instance, if we knew
its value today, we could, in theory, estimate its value as of a year ago or
five years ago, or its projected value a year or five years from now, based
upon the actual or assumed number of nodes/users at each point in time.
To determine “x” at a given point in time, it’s tempting at
first to simply add up the market price of all bitcoins at any given point and
proclaim the sum to be the intrinsic use value of the network. However, doing so is problematic for multiple
reasons, three of which I will mention here.
First, the market price of an individual bitcoin presumably
represents each coin’s proportional share of the expected future value of the network (including its expected future number
of nodes), discounted to the present, rather than its proportional share of the
network’s current value based simply upon its current usefulness (as
approximated by its current number of nodes).
The market price (as opposed to its intrinsic value) of any good reflects
primarily the market’s discounted expectations of the future rather than simply
the circumstances of the present.
Second, because bitcoins are famously volatile, the exact
point of time one chooses to measure the value of an individual bitcoin can
make a huge difference when extrapolating based upon the power law valuation
metrics. For instance, should we determine
“x” based upon a bitcoin’s market price in late December of 2013, when each was
trading for more than $1,000 per coin?
Or today when it’s trading in the mid $200’s?
Third, Bitcoins are increasingly used as a medium of
exchange and store of value and may one day be traded as money. Mises’s regression theorem teaches that, once
a commodity begins taking on attributes of money, its spending power (exchange
value) is no longer limited to its underlying use value as a commodity. Said
another way, additional exchange value (purchasing power) attaches by virtue of
its new function as money such that the commodity trades at a premium versus
its pure commodity use. For instance,
gold (as a store of value and medium of exchange) trades at a significant
premium versus what it would if we esteemed it only for its uses in industry
and for adornment.
The market price of individual bitcoins at any given moment
therefore likely includes a premium to account for the digital token’s growing
use as a store of value and medium of exchange.
Including this “money premium” in the power law metric equations could
skew the results improperly (though arguably the adoption of money is itself
exhibits network effects that may, in fact, also be described by Metcalfe’s law
or the n log(n) formula, as theorized below).
Given the above issues, and others not mentioned, simply
adding up the market price of individual bitcoins at a given moment likely tells
us nothing about the intrinsic usability/value of the Bitcoin network at that
time. Therefore, this practice should be
avoided.
We Can Still Play “What If”
Even so, we can still use the power law valuation metrics to
have some fun. We can, for example, make certain assumptions about Bitcoin’s
value at any given point in time, as well as the future rate of growth in the
number of nodes, and then employ Metcalfe’s law or the n log(n) function to
guesstimate the network’s implied use value at any other point past or
present.
Findings in a recent working paper published by the Division
of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs of the Federal Reserve Board,
Washington, D.C. (available here,
p. 17) give us a starting point. The
study indicates that the number of unique daily users (UDUs) of the Bitcoin
network stood at 100,000 as of “the beginning of 2014” and has doubled every
eight months through the three year period ended then.
If we use UDUs as a proxy for active nodes, if we likewise assume
the paper’s estimated number of UDUs is reasonably accurate, and if we finally assume
that the number of UDU continues to double every eight months into the foreseeable
future, then we can easily calculate the Bitcoin network’s implied use value at
any point in time using the power law valuation metrics, provided know an “x”
value at any point in time.
For instance, applying the above assumptions and assigning the
network an intrinsic use value of $1,150,000 in early August 2013 (just to pick
a number and date), which equates to approximately ten cents per bitcoin at
that time, we get the following implied values:
|
Unique
|
n log(n) Implied
|
Metcalfe Implied
|
Date
|
Daily Users
|
Price Per Coin
|
Price Per Coin
|
12/1/12
|
25,000
|
0.05
|
0.03
|
8/2/13
|
50,000
|
0.10
|
0.10
|
4/3/14
|
100,000
|
0.20
|
0.37
|
12/3/14
|
200,000
|
0.38
|
1.36
|
8/4/15
|
400,000
|
0.76
|
5.08
|
4/4/16
|
800,000
|
1.49
|
18.99
|
12/4/16
|
1,600,000
|
2.94
|
71.37
|
8/5/17
|
3,200,000
|
5.99
|
277.08
|
4/6/18
|
6,400,000
|
12.18
|
1,076.66
|
12/6/18
|
12,800,000
|
24.74
|
4,187.02
|
8/7/19
|
25,600,000
|
50.18
|
16,295.44
|
4/7/20
|
51,200,000
|
101.68
|
63,466.44
|
12/7/20
|
102,400,000
|
205.89
|
247,356.39
|
8/8/21
|
204,800,000
|
427.26
|
989,425.56
|
4/9/22
|
409,600,000
|
885.47
|
3,957,702.24
|
12/9/22
|
819,200,000
|
1,809.63
|
15,630,418.96
|
8/10/23
|
1,638,400,000
|
3,741.50
|
62,521,675.83
|
4/10/24
|
3,276,800,000
|
7,727.47
|
250,086,703.31
|
However, by August 2013, the Bitcoin network was already world’s
most powerful, with eight times more processing power than the world’s fastest
500 supercomputers combined. Since processing power is what secures the
network, the Bitcoin system was by that time incredibly reliable and resistant
to attack. Given the network’s unique
capabilities, its processing power, and its incredible security, perhaps valuing
the network at $1,150,000 in August 2014 is far too conservative.
Consequently, lets assume the intrinsic use value of the
whole network was approximately $11.5 million in August 2013, making each
bitcoin then worth $1.
Under the same assumptions noted above, we then get implied
values as follows:
|
Unique
|
n log(n) Implied
|
Metcalfe Implied
|
Date
|
Daily Users
|
Price Per Coin
|
Price Per Coin
|
12/1/12
|
25,000
|
0.52
|
0.27
|
8/2/13
|
50,000
|
1.00
|
1.00
|
4/3/14
|
100,000
|
1.96
|
3.68
|
12/3/14
|
200,000
|
3.84
|
13.63
|
8/4/15
|
400,000
|
7.56
|
50.76
|
4/4/16
|
800,000
|
14.91
|
189.94
|
12/4/16
|
1,600,000
|
29.45
|
713.70
|
8/5/17
|
3,200,000
|
59.94
|
2,770.82
|
4/6/18
|
6,400,000
|
121.83
|
10,766.63
|
12/6/18
|
12,800,000
|
247.38
|
41,870.22
|
8/7/19
|
25,600,000
|
501.77
|
162,954.38
|
4/7/20
|
51,200,000
|
1,016.85
|
634,664.42
|
12/7/20
|
102,400,000
|
2,058.92
|
2,473,563.90
|
8/8/21
|
204,800,000
|
4,272.59
|
9,894,255.59
|
4/9/22
|
409,600,000
|
8,854.68
|
39,577,022.36
|
12/9/22
|
819,200,000
|
18,096.35
|
156,304,189.57
|
8/10/23
|
1,638,400,000
|
37,415.02
|
625,216,758.28
|
4/10/24
|
3,276,800,000
|
77,274.70
|
2,500,867,033.11
|
As previously noted, one criticism of Metcalfe’s law is that the numbers become unreasonably large as the network grows. I suspect that not even Bitcoin’s most avid proponents believe it likely that individual bitcoins will have the purchasing power of over $1 billion by 2024. For this reason and the others noted above, the n log(n) metric is likely the better guide.
But, perhaps even an $11.5 million intrinsic use value for
the whole network in August 2013 is still too low. If we place the intrinsic use value the
network at $115 million ($10 per coin) at that time, then we get implied values
of:
|
Unique
|
n log(n) Implied
|
Metcalfe Implied
|
Date
|
Daily Users
|
Price Per Coin
|
Price Per Coin
|
12/1/12
|
25,000
|
5.17
|
2.74
|
8/2/13
|
50,000
|
10.00
|
10.00
|
4/3/14
|
100,000
|
19.58
|
36.80
|
12/3/14
|
200,000
|
38.44
|
136.30
|
8/4/15
|
400,000
|
75.64
|
507.59
|
4/4/16
|
800,000
|
149.13
|
1,899.35
|
12/4/16
|
1,600,000
|
294.47
|
7,136.97
|
8/5/17
|
3,200,000
|
599.35
|
27,708.24
|
4/6/18
|
6,400,000
|
1,218.35
|
107,666.29
|
12/6/18
|
12,800,000
|
2,473.78
|
418,702.22
|
8/7/19
|
25,600,000
|
5,017.74
|
1,629,543.78
|
4/7/20
|
51,200,000
|
10,168.45
|
6,346,644.21
|
12/7/20
|
102,400,000
|
20,589.19
|
24,735,638.97
|
8/8/21
|
204,800,000
|
42,725.88
|
98,942,555.90
|
4/9/22
|
409,600,000
|
88,546.76
|
395,770,223.59
|
12/9/22
|
819,200,000
|
180,963.47
|
1,563,041,895.70
|
8/10/23
|
1,638,400,000
|
374,150.22
|
6,252,167,582.78
|
4/10/24
|
3,276,800,000
|
772,747.00
|
25,008,670,331.14
|
Notice once again the problem with Metcalfe’s law: A single bitcoin going for $5 billion or more in 2023? Not likely, and perhaps not even possible. By contrast, the implied n log(n) intrinsic value looks much more reasonable.
Side note: Remember
that the calculations above are designed to estimate the implied intrinsic use
value of the Bitcoin network via application of the power law valuation
metrics. They do not account for the fact that individual bitcoins may trade at a
substantial premium or discount to these calculated values at any given point
in time due to, among other things, speculation, illiquidity, or their
increasing use as a medium of exchange and/or store of value.
One Last Thought on Market Prices
I mentioned previously several reasons why extrapolating
from the market price at any given moment is potentially unwise and
improper. Nonetheless, it’s possible
that this view is mistaken, or at least incomplete, for at least two reasons.
First, given Bitcoin’s novel usefulness, it is very likely
considered by most to be a “speculative” technology, offering great but highly
uncertain and unproven promise.
Consequently, the market likely discounts any expectations regarding
future growth in users to the present at a very high discount rate. Said another way, expectations regarding the
possibility of Bitcoin’s future growth are likely tempered, and perhaps nearly
completely offset (via the market-assigned discount rate), by the uncertainty
of that growth and “unproven” nature of the technology.
If expectations of future network growth are indeed largely
or completely offset by a very high discount rate, then the wild fluctuations in
bitcoin’s price over the last year are not so much a function of speculation as
insufficient liquidity. Illiquid markets
in fixed-supply commodities are notoriously volatile.
Second, focusing on the market price allows us to account
for one piece of potentially valuable information that was not considered in my
calculations above—each bitcoin’s “premium” over its commodity use value, if
any, that results from its increasing use as a store of value and medium of
exchange. In other words, if the
adoption by the public of new stores of value, mediums of exchange, and/or
monies exhibits network effect behaviors consistent with the expectations of
one of power law valuation metrics, then it would be appropriate to add this
premium to each bitcoin’s underlying commodity value before applying them. Presumably this premium, if any, is reflected
in its market price at any given moment.
With the above two considerations in mind, consider that each
bitcoin traded in the market at about $100 per coin in early August 2013, a
fairly stable time in bitcoin’s price history. If we assume use of this price
to be a reasonable estimation of its intrinsic use value and value as money at
the time, without undue distortions or volatility due to lack of liquidity,
then applying the same assumptions as we did in prior calculations, we derive
implied values as follows:
|
Unique
|
n log(n) Implied
|
Metcalfe Implied
|
Date
|
Daily Users
|
Price Per Coin
|
Price Per Coin
|
12/1/12
|
25,000
|
51.66
|
27.38
|
8/2/13
|
50,000
|
100.00
|
100.00
|
4/3/14
|
100,000
|
195.79
|
368.00
|
12/3/14
|
200,000
|
384.40
|
1,362.96
|
8/4/15
|
400,000
|
756.42
|
5,075.86
|
4/4/16
|
800,000
|
1,491.29
|
18,993.55
|
12/4/16
|
1,600,000
|
2,944.70
|
71,369.70
|
8/5/17
|
3,200,000
|
5,993.54
|
277,082.35
|
4/6/18
|
6,400,000
|
12,183.46
|
1,076,662.86
|
12/6/18
|
12,800,000
|
24,737.84
|
4,187,022.22
|
8/7/19
|
25,600,000
|
50,177.43
|
16,295,437.84
|
4/7/20
|
51,200,000
|
101,684.50
|
63,466,442.11
|
12/7/20
|
102,400,000
|
205,891.91
|
247,356,389.74
|
8/8/21
|
204,800,000
|
427,258.81
|
989,425,558.97
|
4/9/22
|
409,600,000
|
885,467.60
|
3,957,702,235.90
|
12/9/22
|
819,200,000
|
1,809,634.69
|
15,630,418,956.96
|
8/10/23
|
1,638,400,000
|
3,741,502.19
|
62,521,675,827.85
|
4/10/24
|
3,276,800,000
|
7,727,469.99
|
250,086,703,311.39
|
Remember, the above calculations are not intended to be
predictions of the actual market price of bitcoins at any given point in time
and shouldn’t be used for such purpose.
Rather, they represent the potential “implied” or “intrinsic” value of
the network and currency (expressed on a per bitcoin basis) calculated using
Metcalfe’s Law and the n log(n) methodology under the stated assumptions.
Conclusion
Bitcoin is fundamentally a network, and a uniquely useful
one at that. Individual bitcoins (or
fractions thereof) represent the exclusive means of gaining write-access to the
Bitcoin network. Importantly, bitcoins
provide such access not as a privilege or right granted by law but rather as a
mathematical requirement of the system itself.
Without bitcoins, transacting via the bitcoin system is physically
impossible.
It’s a tautology to say that useful networks have use value. And because bitcoins are the exclusive means
of accessing the unique Bitcoin network and are limited in supply, they too
have use value. This demonstrates that
bitcoins meet the requirements of Mises’s Regression Theorum.
The two generally-accepted ways of determining the inherent
usefulness of a network is Metcalfe’s law and the n log(n) formula
(collectively herein called the “power law valuation metrics”). Both indicate that the value of a network is
a function of its number of nodes or users, though they disagree as to how much
value each additional node adds. Being
more conservative and seemingly more realistic, the n log(n) formulation is
probably to be preferred.
Both of the power law valuation metrics describe only how
much a network’s value varies as a function of changes in the number of its
nodes. Neither reveals what the network’s
value actually is. To determine actual
value, one must make additional assumptions.
By calculating and/or assuming the number of Bitcoin’s users
(nodes) each year along with a use value for the network at any given point in
time (“x”), we can use the power law valuation metrics to estimate an implied
value per bitcoin at any other given time past or present. Results of these calculations, as indicated
in this essay, vary wildly based upon one’s assumption of “x” and which
valuation metric preferred.
However, despite wild fluctuations in bitcoin’s market price
(likely due primarily to speculation and/or illiquidity), the number of unique
daily users (nodes) of the Bitcoin network has doubled every eight months for
at least the last three years, and the pace of adoption seemingly shows no
signs of diminishing. Consequently, both
of the power law valuation metrics indicate that the intrinsic use value of the
network has grown at an almost steady exponential rate for many years. This suggests that bitcoin’s famous
volatility in market price does not adversely impact network usefulness or slow
the pace of user adoption.
1 comment:
Interesting analysis and well written. One point of contention is that you only consider nodes active users. In reality, most bitcoin users access the Bitcoin network through hosted wallets like Coinbase and Circle or online wallet providers like Blockchain.info. I would argue the users of these services also constitute daily active users and, therefore, should be accounted for in your valuation. For example, how many active email users are there? Only those that operate their own email client (a la Hilary Clinton) or the millions of users that access email through gmail, hotmail, etc.?
Post a Comment